In light of the acquittal in the Icesave case, I see a reason to post the press release from the Ministry for Foreign Affairs in its totality.
The interesting question which now remains is: are deposits in Europe safe? If e.g. Santander goes bankrupt, will the savers in the UK, which have deposited their savings at the Santander branches in the UK, be repaid? (Amongst other things, it depends on whether the Santander operations in the UK are under the umbrella of a branch or a subsidiary of Santander Spain. It also depends on whether the bank is a member of the UK deposit insurance scheme or not). Likewise, will a German customer of Bankia be repaid if the bank goes bankrupt? Who is meant to save Bankia in case of the need of a bailout: the German government? The Spanish one? Both?
Please, do note that I am not with those words questioning the security of UK deposits in Santender UK or German deposits in Bankia. I am merely trying to explain that the deposit insurance schemes in Europe are far from being fully funded and, in light of the acquittal, NOT automatically backed up by the States' finances.
Surely, the plans on creating a pan-European banking regulator will take this acquittal into the account when its formation will be decided.
Here is the press release (italics are mine):
Iceland welcomes acquittal in Icesave case
The EFTA Court ruling on Icesave rejected all claims by the EFTA
Surveillance Authority that Iceland should be declared in breach of the EEA
Agreement. The Court rejected the claim that Iceland has breached the Deposit
Guarantee Directive or has discriminated against depositors contrary to EEA
law. It is a considerable satisfaction that Iceland´s defence has won the day
in the Icesave case; the EFTA Court ruling brings to a close an important stage
in a long saga.
Iceland has from the start maintained that there is legal uncertainty as to
whether a state is responsible for ensuring payments of minimum guarantees to
depositors using its own funds and has stressed the importance of having this
issue clarified in court. There was, however, no realistic possibility of such
clarification until the EFTA Surveillance Authority decided to refer the case
to the EFTA Court.
This judgement concludes the procedures with the EFTA Surveillance Authority
in regard to the Icesave case. The ruling of the EFTA Court is final and cannot
be appealed. This case has been particularly difficult to handle both
nationally and internationally, and has occasioned, among other things,
considerable delays in the implementation of the Government´s economic
programme. Icesave is now no longer a stumbling block to Iceland economic
recovery.
It is important to bear in mind that payments from the estate of the failed
Landsbanki will continue regardless of the ruling of the EFTA Court. The assets
of the estate are now estimated to be 1,517 billion ISK which is approximately
200 billion ISK more than the priority claims which amount to 1,318 billion
ISK. Of these priority claims 1,166 billion ISK result from the Icesave deposits
while just under 150 billion ISK result from wholesale deposits, including
those from municipalities, charities etc. The sum of 660 billion ISK has
already been paid out of the estate against priority claims, i.e. around 50% of
their total value. Of this 585 billion ISK have gone to claims resulting from
the Icesave accounts. This sum amounts to over 90% of the total which the UK
and Dutch authorities advanced to cover the minimum deposit guarantee.
It is expected that the Icesave claims will be paid out in full by the
actual debtor, the estate of the failed Landsbanki. This outcome results from
the implementation of emergency legislation in 2008, according to which
deposits were given priority against unsecured claims.
About the Icelandic Economy, the European Economic Crisis, debt and deflation. "Words ought to be a little wild..."
Monday, 28 January 2013
Thursday, 24 January 2013
The Economic Truth on Iceland
The following article is the original text of the articles published on Sintetia in Spain. The Spanish versions can be found here (part 1) and here (part 2), kindly translated by the Sintetia staff.
The Economic Truth on Iceland
There are truths and untruths in the media, the blogosphere
and in the minds of people when it comes to what really happened in Iceland and
its, acclaimed, economic recovery. To some extent, it has gotten the stamp of
some sort of an economic “Wunderkind” by defying all probabilities and becoming
a poster child about how to respond to major economic crises. But to spill the
beans already: the picture is not as rosy as it has been painted.
Let’s start with some of the claims. According to a less
than a five minute search on the internet, Iceland:
- - Screwed the creditors of the banks and let the banks fail, then nationalised them
- - Jailed the bankers of the failed banks
- - Kicked out the Austerity supporters, the Troika and the IMF in particular
- - Gave huge debt reliefs to the public
- - Set up capital controls which will be abolished very soon, even as soon as this year
- - Is now, consequently, growing and, especially in comparison to debt-laden Europe, doing quite fantastically!
- - Furthermore, not only is it growing but the prospects of the future are wonderful
So the lesson, following Iceland’s example, is to let the
banks fail, nationalise them, increase government spending, shut the capital
inside the economy and give debt reliefs to the people instead of the creditors
of the banks.
Too bad this is not entirely according to the truth. Read on
and I’ll show you how deep the rabbit hole really goes.
What goes up must
come down
There is no need to describe in detail how on Earth this
tiny, but very proud, nation managed to allow itself to be turned into nothing
else than a hedge fund. In short, the utter majority of the nation was
stricken hard by the “This Time Is Different” complex. The people, especially
its bankers, considered themselves to be financial geniuses, not the least due
to their Viking heritage, and went bonkers borrowing money and buying stuff.
“Stuff” included not only general consumption goods and expensive cars but
houses and stocks as well. News of stocks and houses were common and the
general populace seemed to know awfully lot about which company in the stock
exchange had gained most the day before. The equity index in the Icelandic
Stock Exchange increased sixfold in four years: more than 50% per year on
average!
But as the good advice goes: “when your neighbour buys
stocks, it’s time to sell”. Too bad nobody, except a handful of sober persons,
realised the truth in this.
The banks and the
government
The Icelandic economic collapse in October 2008 was
inevitable. No country has ever managed to build up its banking sector up to 10
times the worth of the gross domestic product and lived to tell the tail
unharmed. When Kaupthing, the biggest Icelandic bank, went bankrupt it was the
fourth biggest corporate bankruptcy in the world’s history! Glitnir’s bankruptcy
was number 6 on the list, dwarfing Enron’s which occupied the no. 9 place. Landsbanki’s failure was just cut short of
the top 10, ending in no. 11.
In a time span of less than a week, more than 90%
of Iceland’s banking system, on the scale of assets, went down the drain.
Most of the rest followed in the coming months but was,
contrary to the folklore outside Iceland, bailed out by the Government. SpKef
and Byr, two savings banks, are cases in point. There, the Icelandic bankers’ gluttony
was not lesser than in the case of the big banks. Nevertheless, the
government gave them some cash, casting a terrible shadow on Iceland’s
image as a country which does not bail out banks. Good thing nobody noticed.
SpKef was later assimilated into New Landsbanki (a state owned bank) but Byr
ended up in Islandsbanki (New Glitnir).
It is very important to realise one thing: the governments,
both the “conservative” one prior, during and after the October crash, and the
“left wing” one, which took over after the 2009 general elections, did
everything they could – absolutely
everything – to try and keep the banks afloat. And of course, the banks
themselves tried what they could to save their faces by buying up their own
stocks and thereby maintain their price (which, in their case, was quite close to being a market abuse). The savings banks that went off the cliff after the Big Three had
closed down their shops were small enough to be rescued by the government but
the Big Three in October 2008 were simply too large to be saved. That did not
stop the government from trying everything it could do to throw out the safety
net, including practically emptying the foreign reserves of the Central Bank
when it tried to keep Glitnir afloat.
It was Iceland’s “fool’s luck” not to be able to rescue the
banks in October 2008. I don’t want to even consider the cost of rescuing the
banks today, it would have been horrible! The 31%-of-GDP public deficit in Ireland
in 2011 would have been a laughing stock compared to the gargantuan cost the
Icelandic public coffers would have suffered if the banks had been saved.
The jails in Iceland
are not full of “banksters”
So the first lore on Iceland – that it intentionally let the
banks to bankrupt – is not according to reality. The reality is that the
government tried to save them but could not. The one about all the jailed
banksters is, well, not entirely true either.
Let’s take two examples:
The Al Thani Plot
Kaupthing famously got the brother of the emir of Qatar,
Sheik Al Thani, to buy stock in the bank. Later, The Special Prosecutor
(specially founded to deal with white collar crimes) charged the CEO of
Kaupthing, Hreidar Mar Sigurdsson, and the chairman of the board of directors
of Kaupthing, Sigurdur Einarsson for fraud (Einarsson is the son of late Einar Agustsson,
ex Minister of Foreign Affairs and MP of The Progressive Party, the political
party which had hands in the sales of Bunadarbanki which was later to become
Kaupthing-Bunadarbanki and, in the end, Kaupthing... just an example of how
close business and politics were and are in Iceland).
Why the charges of fraud? Well, apparently, the Sheik didn’t
pay a dime for the 5% share in Kaupthing Bank, he simply lent his name to the
fraudulent act and got
50 million USD for it! The Al Thani case is still in the courthouse but the
charge against Olafur Olafsson, the CEO/chairman of the board of directors of Samskip and the third biggest owner in
Kaupthing and a member of the team which bought Bunadarbankinn in the
beginning, has been dismissed. The charge against Magnus Gudmundsson, the ex
CEO of Kaupthing Luxembourg, was also dismissed. But the charges against
Sigurdsson and Einarsson stand.
The Exeter Holdings
Plot
Exeter Holdings was an asset holding company (we had many!)
which was lent 1.1 billion ISK from Byr (the savings bank which got some cash
from the government before finally being assimilated into Islandsbanki) which
then was used to buy Byr stock of MP Bank and the men in charge of Byr. Then,
Byr practically went bankrupt and went, hat in hand, to the government and got
some cash from it, as already mentioned.
So Byr was used, just before it went bankrupt, to lend money
to Exeter Holdings which then bailed MP Bank and the senior employers in charge
of Byr out of their positions in the Byr stock. Very convenient to know that if
your stock is just about to become worthless you can just lend some asset
holding company ridiculous amount of money and bail yourself out.
The charged (Ragnar Z. Gudjonsson, CEO, Jon Thorsteinn
Jonsson, chairman of the board of directors, and Styrmir Bragason, CEO of MP
Bank) were originally all acquitted. But then somebody pointed out that one of
the judges who acquitted them was connected to Byr: he
was the Head of Legal Department in a company whose biggest owner was, you
guessed it, Byr savings bank. The case was repeated, now with unconnected
judges, and Gudjonsson and Jonsson got four
and a half year (Maddoff got 150 years and a fine of 17 billion USD).
Bragason is, as far as I’m aware off, still waiting his destiny.
The Exeter case is the most successful case which The
Special Prosecutor has carried out. The Al Thani plot is, however, one where the scheme
is so complicated that a single misstep by the Prosecutor can ruin the whole
case. Another complicated case was the recent “Vafnings case” which was only
partially successful for the Prosecutor. For although the charged, Larus
Welding, CEO of Glitnir, and Gudmundur Hjaltason, head of Corporate Finance at
Glitnir, were found guilty, the case was flawed: the prosecutor’s arguments
were not fully according to the subpoena. So they only got 9 months
imprisonment, thereof 6 months suspended.
The fundamental factor is that neither the Icelandic
justice system nor the laws themselves are ready or meant for white collar
crimes of the magnitude that took place before, during and after the collapse.
And we certainly do not have an army of lawyers specialised in fighting white
collar crimes, contrary to many other countries where experience and knowledge are abound. Combine all this together and the most likely, sometimes unfortunately and sometimes correctly,
outcome of the “banksters’ cases” in Iceland is that they walk either entirely
free or with only a firm slap on the buttocks. This is so not because they are all
innocent but because the justice system is unprepared. This is, somewhat, a
learning-by-doing process.
Iceland, the IMF and
the austerity
There are some truths in the story that Iceland objected to
the IMF’s original plans of “medium-term fiscal consolidation” as it was worded
in the IMF reports on Iceland. However, the objections were rather half-hearted,
especially before the “left-wing” coalition government got into power in early
2009. Lilja Mosesdottir, an economist with a PhD in economics from University
of Manchester (her thesis: “The political economy of gender relations”) was one
of the MPs that were loudest about the possibility that IMF might be applying
the knife on the public finances in too large measures. Those objections were
perhaps more prominent for the fact that Mosesdottir was, back then, an MP for
the Left-Green Party (one of two parties in the coalition government) but left
it to protest what she called the servility of the government towards IMF. So
not everybody in Iceland was exuberant with IMF’s presence although the “left-wing”
government seemed not to care too much.
IMF was however quite happy with how Iceland came out of the
crisis, whether that was explicitly thanks to their policies or not. They were
in fact so proud of the economic Wunderkind that Iceland proved itself to be –
according to them at least, I’m not sure the Johns and Joneses of Iceland would
agree – that they threw a conference to highlight the successes of the country.
Cannons within the economics world gave speeches and the biggest cannon of them
all was probably Paul Krugman.
Contrary to what one might think the conference was not an
absolute muddle of self-appraisal and some of the talks were very informative
and exemplary (Simon Johnson’s talk was absolutely spectacular!) And IMF did
show that it had learned something! For example, it openly and very willingly
admitted that capital controls are “in some circumstances” an appropriate
reaction to a crisis. That, on its own, was a huge step forward compared to its
thinking in the South-East Asian crisis in the late 90’s. You can check out a
recording of the conference on the IMF
website.
Ah, yes... the debt
relief...
Right, let’s get one thing straight from the beginning: the Icelandic
households did not receive a massive government-initiated debt jubilee!
What the households got from the government was “The 110% Measure”
(if your mortgage was higher than 110% of the property’s market value, you
would get the principal marked down to the 110% mark) and “The Abstract Debt
Relief” which you were only applicable to enter if you were in “serious” debt
difficulties.
The total household debt cancelled due to those
government-initiated measures: 49.8 billion ISK. To make any sense out of that
figure: the debt of Icelandic households just before the economic collapse in
October 2008 amounted to more than 1,450 billion ISK. So the government managed
to give the Icelandic households a debt jubilee on 3-4% of their debts. Hooray!
Then came the justice system’s surprise input.
It all started with some individuals trying to figure out
what the heck had gone wrong. Somebody stumbled over the fact that
foreign-currency linked loans seemed to have been illegal from 2001. That
possible illegality had not stopped the banks from creating billions and
billions worth of mortgages and car loans to individuals as well as general
credit contracts to firms in Icelandic krona but linked to the exchange rate of
a foreign currency. This was doubtful at best. In the end, the foreign-currency
linked loans were deemed illegal after a fight which still isn’t over (they are
still arguing which types of foreign-currency linked loans are illegal).
But here is a wonderful twist for those who think that the
government was all into giving the households some debt relief.
After the foreign-currency linked loans had
been deemed illegal by the Supreme Court the government stepped in and put into
effect a retroactive law that had the
effects that the banks got a lot more out of the loans than they should have
had. Likewise, the households’ debt was higher than if the laws had not been
passed.
Again the door of the court room was swung open and now the
laws that the government itself had put into effect were in the bull’s eye.
They were finally deemed illegal, exactly because of their retroactivity, and
the households’ loans were corrected. And what they got: a correction amounting
to 146.8 billion ISK – almost triple what the government gave them and that
despite the fact that the “left-wing” government had tried to intervene with a retroactive law.
So in total, the Icelandic households have been given a debt
jubilee of 196.3 billion ISK. That’s around 13% of the pre-crisis stock of debt
they had, mostly coming from the fight against the illegal foreign-currency
loans.
However, despite this cancellation of 13% of the total debt,
the stock of households’ debt has grown again. And why is that? It’s not
predominately because households have gone back on the spending spree they
admittedly were on before the crash. It is because of the indexation of the
principal of mortgages in Iceland: if inflation in Iceland is 5% the amount you
owe the bank increases by 5% before you pay it back! On top of the
rate-of-inflation-adjustment of the principal is a 4-5% rate of interest.
And
since the inflation in Iceland since October 2008 is 25%, one can understand
why the debt of households in Iceland is not falling in accordance to what one
might think with the 13% jubilee and general debt deflation in mind. In
comparison to gross domestic product, households’ debt is now around 117% of
GDP (year end 2011) compared to 127% of GDP before the crash.
So I’m sorry, but the (in)famous debt jubilee given to
Icelandic households was a mere cough.
‘If I go there will
be trouble, and if I stay it will be double!’
We’ve shortly commented on the existence of the capital
controls and how IMF had realised that they were a powder keg that could be
nice to have in the anti-crisis arsenal. Too bad for the South-East Asian
countries they did not realise that earlier.
Generally, capital controls are considered to be a nuisance
in economics, although in practice they have shown themselves to be quite an
attractive choice when it comes to not only responding to an ongoing crisis but
to stop the crisis from happening in the first place. Nevertheless, the issue
is slippery and capital controls open up the possibility of malinvestment,
favouritism (some get exceptions from the capital controls) and a black market
with currency. None are favourable so it’s most often best to get rid of
capital controls. At least, their application has to be scrupulously planned!
All this is too bad because the capital controls were
erected in a panic in 2008 and now the IMF has, finally, realised that
the “short term” nature of them might not be so short term (“while the
external position [of the economy] is sound, it is vulnerable to the lifting of
capital controls before conditions are right”].
In other words, if we lift the capital controls and allow
the exchange rate to drop by maybe 25-50% (as it easily might do, the offshore
exchange rate of the krona is about 40% weaker than the
capital-controls-defended exchange rate within the Icelandic economy) the
economy will go to hell! So much for the economic Wunderkind then!
Sorry, but if some seriously heterodox ointments are not
applied to the exchange-rate problem, the capital controls are here to stay!
And that’s problematic given their general negative impact on the economy,
hence above.
The thing is that the heterodox ointments needed have been
proposed already. They are just so heterodox that the government, the IMF and
the country’s “Lords of
Finance” don’t even want to consider it. This is so despite the fact that
the ointments have been applied before in the economic history of other
countries with such immediate and lasting improvements that they surprised
everybody – except the people who applied them. The German Wirtschaftswunder is
an excellent example of the heterodox ointments we are talking about.
But why the recovery?
The question why
the economy rebounded has not been answered however. But Richard C. Koo gave
the answer to that question two years ago with his “The world in a balance
sheet recession” paper. And the answer was this: the Icelandic economy is
in a “Lehman Brothers Shock” except of course in the case of Iceland we can say
it was in an “Utter Banking Failures Shock”.
The argument is as follows. First, an economy experiences a
(mad) debt bubble. When the Ponzi finances inherited in the debt bubble finally
prick it, asset prices fall and the economy slows down, the threat is that a
major financial institution goes under. That was Lehman Brothers in the United
States but in the case of Iceland, it was the whole financial system.
That bankruptcy, obviously, brings a massive blow to the
economy and it drops like a stone thrown off the edge of the leaning tower in
Pisa. But when the economic panic recedes and commerce returns – people have to
eat – the economy slowly bounces back from its lowest panic-ridden point. An
exchange crash which brings an increase in tourism helps as well.
That natural
bounce-back is the economic recovery of Iceland! There is nothing
surprising to the economic growth in Iceland, it is an entirely normal response
to an “Utter Banking Failures Shock”: the mere recovery from the absolute panic
brings back the growth in output and with it, the economic growth. The problem
is that the debts are still there and the underlying foundations can crack
anytime.
Koo’s paper is extraordinarily clear on this point: the
recovery from the “Utter Banking Failures Shock” is NOT a recovery from
underlying debt problems which, in fact, caused the “Utter Banking Failures
Shock” in the first place. And given how weak the economic foundations of
Iceland really are, Koo’s answer is awfully correct.
Furthermore, is an economic growth of 2-3% something to be
thrilled over? In the historical context: not really. But in comparison to
southern Europe: most definitely! That’s maybe why the meagre growth Iceland
has gained back is causing such a stir.
‘The long run is a
misleading guide to current affairs. In the long run, we are all dead.’
So there you have it. The cosy picture drawn of the economic
miracle of Iceland has serious stains on it. Despite the fact that the economy
has, partially, rebounded to its pre-crisis level, the underlying foundations
are so termite-infested that the slightest wind could blow the whole economy to
kingdom come! That applies especially to the problem of abolishing the capital
controls.
And although Iceland has clean energy, a happy populace, is
growing again (at least for the moment) and many possibilities of being a
paradise on Earth for the longer run, it is not that which matters. We must
remember what Keynes taught us: “The long run is a misleading guide to current
affairs.” And why is that? Because “in the long run, we are all dead.” To say
that everything will be fine in the far future is useless if we die before the
far future finally arrives.
But did we do something right? Yes, we did!
- - We did step up against the IMF and although it was half-hearted at best, it probably preserved most of what could be preserved of the welfare system and the general economic stabilisers of public expenditures.
- - We did introduce the debt jubilee and out of principle we must congratulate us for that for even though it was a downright band-aid on an open gunshot wound, it was at least done. So debt jubilees are possible (and quite frankly, some countries need a partial one, whether we want to admit that or not).
- - Last but not least: we saved the electronic payment system! To maintain the smooth operation of an electronic payment system in a country whose financial system is falling into atom particles is a terrific feat on its own!
Truth be told, the major lesson Iceland has for other
countries is how to keep the electronic payment system alive during a massive
financial storm. That lesson has gone completely under the radar and I don’t
think a single foreign entity or a central bank has picked it up as of yet! It
nevertheless, to a great extent, annuls the “Too Big To Fail” problem for the
commercial banking system so the lesson is gargantuan and its worth
inconceivable!
I will cover that lesson in more detail in my upcoming book,
working title “Bad Economics: How Iceland’s stupid economic policies bankrupted
the country” (an
excerpt available here). In the book I will explain as well how the completely
mad indexation of mortgages works, how the pension system is a major financial
illness and why the Second Economic Crash of Iceland is around the corner.
For
the economic Wunderkind has cancer.
Tuesday, 15 January 2013
"Stock prices have reached what looks like a permanently high plateau"
If only that would be true...
Blatant signs are for a classic bubble forming on the Icelandic stock exchange - again! Since the beginning of the year, stock prices have practically reached a lift-off speed and defied the market's law of gravity.
Why this happens one can only speculate about but a not so unlikely spark is the existence of the capital controls which prevent the Johns and Jonases of Iceland to take their money out of the economy. Investors are therefore locked in, searching for investment opportunities in despair.
Many have parked their money in the banking system with its government backup. Others have funded the increased stock of bonds - especially government bonds as touched upon here - but the market value of registered bonds has risen up to 2,160 billion ISK from 1,390 billion ISK in October 2008. The yield of government bonds has dropped significantly as well, dipping below the yield which would neutralise the actuarial calculations of the Icelandic pension funds but they control around 55% of the total worth of registered bonds in the Icelandic stock exchange. Something tells me that the Icelandic pension funds may not be so eager to hold the too-low-yield-for-them bonds anymore once they will be allowed to invest again abroad.
Other trapped investors have decided to jump on the equities bandwagon, especially after the media began to show the price developments on the stock market some interest (such as here, here, here and here). Like you can count on women flocking to the shops of Paris during the "soldes" period, investors followed the crowd and poured money into the stock market: the turnover of stocks in the first days of the year 2013 was fivefold the average turnover in 2012. Can anybody smell the "permanency" of this newly found stock plateau?
Nothing lasts forever, all stock runs run out in the long run. But who cares about the long run anyway! In the long run we're all dead and today's politicians (and Lords of Finance) will have managed to throw the burden of steering the economy away from recreating the financial turmoil of 2008 onto somebody else's new and unexpected shoulders. And of course the poor soul who is unlucky enough to be in command at the time of the burst of the bubble will take all the blame.
So jump on the bandwagon, enjoy the Beauty Contest and make money beyond your wildest dreams. Just don't come running back to me when you lose them all.
Blatant signs are for a classic bubble forming on the Icelandic stock exchange - again! Since the beginning of the year, stock prices have practically reached a lift-off speed and defied the market's law of gravity.
The stock index in the Icelandic stock exchange. Taken from Keldan.is. Click to enlarge.
Why this happens one can only speculate about but a not so unlikely spark is the existence of the capital controls which prevent the Johns and Jonases of Iceland to take their money out of the economy. Investors are therefore locked in, searching for investment opportunities in despair.
Many have parked their money in the banking system with its government backup. Others have funded the increased stock of bonds - especially government bonds as touched upon here - but the market value of registered bonds has risen up to 2,160 billion ISK from 1,390 billion ISK in October 2008. The yield of government bonds has dropped significantly as well, dipping below the yield which would neutralise the actuarial calculations of the Icelandic pension funds but they control around 55% of the total worth of registered bonds in the Icelandic stock exchange. Something tells me that the Icelandic pension funds may not be so eager to hold the too-low-yield-for-them bonds anymore once they will be allowed to invest again abroad.
Other trapped investors have decided to jump on the equities bandwagon, especially after the media began to show the price developments on the stock market some interest (such as here, here, here and here). Like you can count on women flocking to the shops of Paris during the "soldes" period, investors followed the crowd and poured money into the stock market: the turnover of stocks in the first days of the year 2013 was fivefold the average turnover in 2012. Can anybody smell the "permanency" of this newly found stock plateau?
Nothing lasts forever, all stock runs run out in the long run. But who cares about the long run anyway! In the long run we're all dead and today's politicians (and Lords of Finance) will have managed to throw the burden of steering the economy away from recreating the financial turmoil of 2008 onto somebody else's new and unexpected shoulders. And of course the poor soul who is unlucky enough to be in command at the time of the burst of the bubble will take all the blame.
So jump on the bandwagon, enjoy the Beauty Contest and make money beyond your wildest dreams. Just don't come running back to me when you lose them all.
Wednesday, 9 January 2013
The non-indexed mistake of the Icelandic government
"By a continuing process of inflation, government can confiscate, secretly and unobserved, an important part of the wealth of their citizens."
- John Maynard Keynes
I've mentioned before (here and here) that indexation in Iceland is a peculiar beast. In the first post on the indexation I mentioned that the main issuer of indexed (to the Consumer Price Index) securities in Iceland is not the government but households. In most countries, households wouldn't even think of taking a CPI-indexed loan but for a long time there was nothing else offered in Iceland. Normally, it is the government which issues the indexed bonds. We have e.g. the TIPS in the US, the indexed Gilts in UK and many others (see a Wikipedia list here).
We do things differently in Iceland. Off the CPI-indexed bonds registered in the Icelandic Stock Exchange, 83% of them (based on market value) are Housing Financing Funds bonds which are used to finance the mortgages to households through the HFF. The HFF has a government insurance behind it in case of lack of liquidity or equity, but the HFF is nothing else than an intermediary of indexed debt which the households are effectively issuing. And it is the households which have to carry the first part of the burden in case of problems. HFF can e.g. increase the interest rate mark-up and repossess one's house if the indexed mortgage is not repaid before the government's coffers are opened up to bail the bankrupt HFF out of trouble - which has happened recently and will only happen again given the awful financial cold the fund is suffering.
This misallocation of the burdens of indexation creates a perverted incentive for the government and a massive problem in the wake of that which only hits the government itself in the back of its head.
As its debt is predominantly non-indexed to the rate of inflation, the government has limited reason to make sure that price increases are not excessive. Possibly, it might even want to "inflate" its debt away by allowing inflation to be just a bit higher than it would have if the incentive to "inflate away" wasn't there. But of course, too much inflation would lay waste to the balance sheet of households and that is, unfortunately, somewhat what has happened.
Let's take an example. The bailout money the government raised by issuing bonds to investors was, as one can see by glancing on the graph above, almost entirely in non-indexed bonds (this does not include the foreign-currency bailout money we got from the Scandinavian nations, the IMF etc.) The total market value of non-indexed government bonds, partly because of a lower rate of interest but mainly due to new issuances, increased by a spectacular 539 per cent between year end 2007 and year end 2010 when all the savings-bank bailouts were passed and the reconstruction of the financial system was, for the time being, finished. (Not included in this increase is the bond which was issued to strengthen the equity base of the Central Bank of Iceland after it became technically bankrupt (negative or too low equity) for that bond is simply kept in the Central Bank and not on the market.)
Why was the bailout money not raised in the form of indexed government bonds? Was it because the government did not want to carry the full cost of the bailout and instead throw it on the shoulders of households whose debts are to a large extent indexed?
Who knows! But what we do know is that the government has been raising taxes since the collapse to raise money for the bailout. Tax increases, especially VAT and excise taxes, raise the CPI (although they have nothing to with actual inflation!) and that increases the cost of CPI-indexed bonds. "Luckily" for the government, that cost is not in place for it since the debt it has issued in the recent years is, as already highlighted, mainly non-indexed.
But of course, the CPI increases, caused e.g. by higher taxes and possible pet-projects of perverse politicians, affect the indexation of households' debt. So the indexation-cost comes on top of the increased tax burden for households, adding insult to injury. Of course, this all ends up with a record number of delinquencies and defaults, which again means that the HFF suffers losses as well. Those losses are first borne by the households but when they cannot continue paying, the government, originally trying to reasonably inflate its debt away, has to step in and boost the equity foundations of the HFF. Recently, 13 billion ISK of government money were earmarked for the fund. That amount will only grow in the future.
So the government, by issuing almost only non-indexed debt after the collapse, tried to sway away from an important incentive it should face to help keeping inflation at bay. Instead, the government created, intentionally or not, a reason for itself to allow inflation to increase and inflate its debt burden away: the CPI has increased by 25% since October 2008.
But at the same time, increased inflation only increases the debt burden of indexed mortgages and bankrupts the household sector. Then, "what goes around, comes around" and the government experiences unpleasant but repeated visits from the Housing Financing Fund as the bankruptcies of households ruin its balance sheet and it needs more and more equity injections.
Maybe the government should have stopped fooling around long time ago and issue indexed debt contracts instead, thereby joining the anti-inflation team instead of boosting the ranks of the other team? Luckily, it's not too late yet to switch sides!
- John Maynard Keynes
I've mentioned before (here and here) that indexation in Iceland is a peculiar beast. In the first post on the indexation I mentioned that the main issuer of indexed (to the Consumer Price Index) securities in Iceland is not the government but households. In most countries, households wouldn't even think of taking a CPI-indexed loan but for a long time there was nothing else offered in Iceland. Normally, it is the government which issues the indexed bonds. We have e.g. the TIPS in the US, the indexed Gilts in UK and many others (see a Wikipedia list here).
We do things differently in Iceland. Off the CPI-indexed bonds registered in the Icelandic Stock Exchange, 83% of them (based on market value) are Housing Financing Funds bonds which are used to finance the mortgages to households through the HFF. The HFF has a government insurance behind it in case of lack of liquidity or equity, but the HFF is nothing else than an intermediary of indexed debt which the households are effectively issuing. And it is the households which have to carry the first part of the burden in case of problems. HFF can e.g. increase the interest rate mark-up and repossess one's house if the indexed mortgage is not repaid before the government's coffers are opened up to bail the bankrupt HFF out of trouble - which has happened recently and will only happen again given the awful financial cold the fund is suffering.
The market value of debt securities in the Icelandic Stock Exchange. The predominant issuer of indexed marketable securities is the household sector through the indexed HFF bonds.
This misallocation of the burdens of indexation creates a perverted incentive for the government and a massive problem in the wake of that which only hits the government itself in the back of its head.
As its debt is predominantly non-indexed to the rate of inflation, the government has limited reason to make sure that price increases are not excessive. Possibly, it might even want to "inflate" its debt away by allowing inflation to be just a bit higher than it would have if the incentive to "inflate away" wasn't there. But of course, too much inflation would lay waste to the balance sheet of households and that is, unfortunately, somewhat what has happened.
Let's take an example. The bailout money the government raised by issuing bonds to investors was, as one can see by glancing on the graph above, almost entirely in non-indexed bonds (this does not include the foreign-currency bailout money we got from the Scandinavian nations, the IMF etc.) The total market value of non-indexed government bonds, partly because of a lower rate of interest but mainly due to new issuances, increased by a spectacular 539 per cent between year end 2007 and year end 2010 when all the savings-bank bailouts were passed and the reconstruction of the financial system was, for the time being, finished. (Not included in this increase is the bond which was issued to strengthen the equity base of the Central Bank of Iceland after it became technically bankrupt (negative or too low equity) for that bond is simply kept in the Central Bank and not on the market.)
Why was the bailout money not raised in the form of indexed government bonds? Was it because the government did not want to carry the full cost of the bailout and instead throw it on the shoulders of households whose debts are to a large extent indexed?
Who knows! But what we do know is that the government has been raising taxes since the collapse to raise money for the bailout. Tax increases, especially VAT and excise taxes, raise the CPI (although they have nothing to with actual inflation!) and that increases the cost of CPI-indexed bonds. "Luckily" for the government, that cost is not in place for it since the debt it has issued in the recent years is, as already highlighted, mainly non-indexed.
But of course, the CPI increases, caused e.g. by higher taxes and possible pet-projects of perverse politicians, affect the indexation of households' debt. So the indexation-cost comes on top of the increased tax burden for households, adding insult to injury. Of course, this all ends up with a record number of delinquencies and defaults, which again means that the HFF suffers losses as well. Those losses are first borne by the households but when they cannot continue paying, the government, originally trying to reasonably inflate its debt away, has to step in and boost the equity foundations of the HFF. Recently, 13 billion ISK of government money were earmarked for the fund. That amount will only grow in the future.
Chart III-7 in the 2012/2 Financial Stability Report by the Central Bank of Iceland
So the government, by issuing almost only non-indexed debt after the collapse, tried to sway away from an important incentive it should face to help keeping inflation at bay. Instead, the government created, intentionally or not, a reason for itself to allow inflation to increase and inflate its debt burden away: the CPI has increased by 25% since October 2008.
But at the same time, increased inflation only increases the debt burden of indexed mortgages and bankrupts the household sector. Then, "what goes around, comes around" and the government experiences unpleasant but repeated visits from the Housing Financing Fund as the bankruptcies of households ruin its balance sheet and it needs more and more equity injections.
Maybe the government should have stopped fooling around long time ago and issue indexed debt contracts instead, thereby joining the anti-inflation team instead of boosting the ranks of the other team? Luckily, it's not too late yet to switch sides!
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)