In my first entry about Icelandic indexation of debt and
credit, predominantly mortgages, I touched on how the cost of inflation is
added onto the principal of the mortgage instead of being in the form of higher
nominal rates as is the case in most other countries. The feedback I got from
one of my readers was “I still don’t understand how this thing works, it looks
nuts the way you describe it and it can’t be right.”
I’m sorry, but it is. But admittedly, I didn’t explain in enough
detail how the principal first grows and then contracts only much later in the
loan period. Second, I didn’t explain how or why the monthly payments are
growing exponentially in nominal terms as the loan closes in on its terminal
date. So I hope this post clarifies some of the grey zones that I left in the
first part about Icelandic indexation.
An example
The best way to explain the functionality of anything is, in
my humble opinion, always to take an example. To make things more coherent
between this part of the story and the first I’m going to use the same loan and
the same given figures. They were: an indexed mortgage of 20.000.000 ISK for 40
years at 5.0% real (NOT nominal) interest rates. Payments are monthly and
calculated on an annuity basis, i.e. every single monthly payment (monthly
payment = repayment of principal + interests) should be equal given a certain
principal that is repaid over the loan period and fixed interest rates. Average
inflation is 2.5% (which is the inflation target of Central Bank of Iceland).
The following screen shot from Excel shows how this mortgage
would develop in the beginning, i.e. the first year of 40. Notice that the
borrower does not owe “remainder of original nominal principal” but “remainder
of inflation-compensated principal after payment” once he has dutifully paid
the monthly payment. And that amount grows spectacularly in the beginning of
the loan period.
Table 1: The development of an indexed mortgage in Iceland. Notice that the "remainder of the inflation-compensated principal after payment" grows even though payment has been carried out (click to enlarge).
In fact, it continues to grow, in the case of only 2.5%
inflation, until month 212 (for almost 18 years!) when it finally tops in
24,055,720 ISK. Notice that at that time, the original nominal principal has
shrunk down to 15,487,314 ISK. But again, that’s not what the borrower owes. He
owes 24,055,720 ISK after having paid dutifully of the mortgage for 17 years
and 8 months. And the original amount borrowed was 20,000,000 ISK.
Table 2: The principal owed does not begin to shrink in nominal terms until after almost 18 years in case of the mortgage listed in table 1 (click to enlarge).
But 2.5% inflation is low in Iceland. If we put more
historically reasonable inflation rate of 5% (average annual inflation from
1990 to 2010 was 5.2%) the inflation-compensated principal doesn’t begin to
shrink until after – hold your breath – 25 years and 11 months. By that time,
the nominal amount owed has in fact more
than doubled!
Table 3: 5% inflation is historically lot more realistic in Iceland than 2.5%. In that case, the amount owed more than doubles before it begins to finally shrink after almost 26 years (only 14 years left of the loan period, click to enlarge).
For a more detailed comparison, the graph below shows the
development of the principal owed in the case of 2.5% annual inflation on one
hand but 5% inflation on the other.
Graph 1: The development of the amount owed (ISK) on the mortgage in tables 1-3, given 5% annual inflation or 2.5%.
An enlightening graph is also the development of the monthly
payments (payment = monthly repayment of [inflation compensated] principal +
interests) in the cases of 2.5% and 5% inflation. The graph below shows the
monthly total payments. In the case of 5% annual inflation over the whole loan
period – remember the average annual inflation for the last 20 years is 5.2% - the
monthly repayment grows by a factor 7. This is not a joke! From this graph one
can also estimate that a person who borrowed money with an indexed 40 year
mortgage 20 years ago is paying today about 2.5 times more than in the
beginning of the loan period. Anyone who wants to bet this person to be
bankrupt in 10 years? And does anyone want to think about the feedback between
inflation and necessary nominal wages-after-tax? We’ll come to that in later
posts.
Graph 2: The monthly total repayments grow exponentially. The higher the inflation is, the higher is the exponential growth. Notice that in the case of 5% inflation, the borrower will in the end pay 7 times higher nominal amount than he did in the beginning of the loan period.
But why does the principal not shrink?
Because the cost of inflation – the indexation – is added
onto the principal instead of being included in higher nominal interest rates
as is the case of almost every single mortgage system in the world (apparently
Chile and Israel, of all countries, do something similar to this but I’ve never
found the necessary data to do a complete comparison between the systems. The
Central Bank of Iceland loves to make reference to those economies whenever it
is challenged on whether the Icelandic system is clever or not. If somebody can
tell me anything about the indexation of mortgages in Israel and Chile, please
contact me, it would be most appreciated!)
I hope this explains somewhat better the madness of the Icelandic
indexation. If you’ve got a feeling that this system cannot work out you’re
most profoundly right! But the rabbit hole goes deep and we are getting closer
on being able to discover it properly now that, I hope, the functionality of
the indexation is somewhat clearer.
If there are any questions that are still left unanswered or
you’ve got any other comments, leave them in the comment box and I’ll do my
best to answer them. If there are a lot of troubling matters still left to be
dealt with – beside the sheer shock of thinking men that some nation thought it
might be a good idea to organise its mortgages in such a spectacularly mad way
– I’ll try to clarify them further in later post(s).
But surely, I haven’t even begun introducing you to the
madness of Icelandic economics. Wait until I explain the pension system!